Contents
Financial markets are not macro information efficient. This means that investment decisions miss out on ample relevant macroeconomic data and facts. Information goes to waste due to costs, trading restrictions and external effects. Good research is expensive and only profitable if other market participants are poorly informed. Research findings are not generally tradable. And leakage of proprietary information is inevitable. Evidence of macro information inefficiency includes sluggishness of position changes, popularity of simple investment rules, and prevalence of herding. The implication is that traders that are more efficient in using macro information can produce investment (and social) value.
A simple and practical enhancement of macro information efficiency is the construction of quantamental indicators. A quantamental indicator is a time series that represents the state of an investment-relevant fundamental feature in real-time. The term ‘fundamental’ means that these data inform directly on economic activity, unlike market prices, which inform only indirectly. The key benefits of quantamental indicators are that [1] they fit machine learning pipelines and algorithmic trading tools, thus making a broad set of macro information tradable, [2] they support the consistent use of macro information, [3] they can be applied across traders (or programs), strategy types and asset classes and are, thus, cost-efficient.
Macro information here refers to public information on the economy and its key sectors that is relevant for the pricing of assets and derivatives. This type of information includes economic data (on growth, inflation, confidence, and so forth), government and corporate balance sheets, financial market data (including turnover and open interest), social and political developments, and even environmental and weather trends.
The information efficiency of an asset market is defined as the extent to which the price of the asset reflects available information. Importantly, the efficiency of a market does not mean efficient use of information across all market participants. Different individuals or institutions have different capacities to buy, collect and use data. This is one key reason why there is trading and rational herding behavior (view post here). Herding is rational for uninformed but flexible traders when important releases are forthcoming and some market participants are likely to have private advance information. An information-efficient market produces, researches, and applies macro information to the extent that investment returns and social benefits exceed information costs.
Academic literature often neglects information and research costs, which is not without irony. For the case of negligible information costs, Burton Malkiel (1992) offers a stricter efficiency condition: “A capital market is…efficient if it fully and correctly reflects all relevant information in determining security prices. Formally, the market is said to be efficient with respect to some information set…if the security price would be unaffected by revealing that information to all participants.”
The principal obstacles to information efficiency are costs, trading restrictions, and external effects. In their seminal article “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets” Grossman and Stiglitz explained that since price-relevant information comes at a cost it will only be procured to the extent that inefficient markets allow translating it into sufficient returns: ” The only way informed traders can earn a return on their activity of information gathering, is if they can use their information to take positions in the market which are ‘better’ than the positions of uninformed traders…Hence the assumptions that all markets, including that for information, are always in equilibrium and always perfectly arbitraged are inconsistent when arbitrage is costly” (view journal article here). This theory shows what practitioners already know: investment in information involves a trade-off between cost and return, with no guarantee that markets set asset prices close to their fundamental value.
Acknowledging the cost-return trade-off, the theory of rational inattention provides a model of how market participants manage their scarcity of attention (view post here). In general, people cannot continuously process and act upon all information, but they can set priorities and choose the mistakes they are willing to make. Rational inattention explains why agents pay disproportionate attention to popular variables, simplify the world into a small set of indicators, pay more attention in times of uncertainty, and limit their range of actions.
Theory and practice show that investment managers only collect information and engage in research if costs are contained, if the overall market is not already well informed, and if the information advantage can remain confidential:
Moreover, research alone does not produce efficient markets. Financial markets research translates into price information only if it is acted upon. Alas, the link between research and actual investment flows is often tenuous, for various reasons.
Even if some market participants have superior information and do rationally trade on it, there is no guarantee that their trading will make the overall market more information efficient. As Markus Brunnermeier (2005) illustrated: “While information leakage makes the price process more informative in the short-run, it reduces its informativeness in the long-run…A trader who receives a noisy signal about a forthcoming public announcement can exploit it twice. First, when he receives it, and second, after the public announcement since he knows best the extent to which his information is already reflected in the pre-announcement price. Given his information he expects the price to overshoot and intends to partially revert his trade.” In summary, “obstructions to information diffusion” are common. This means that relevant information and research translate into gradual price trends rather than instantaneous price adjustments (view post here). Gradual diffusion directly conflicts with Eugene Fama’s requirement that an “efficient market is a market which adjusts rapidly to new information.”. Indeed, sluggish price adjustment seems to go a long way in explaining unexpected deviations of financial markets from a rational expectations equilibrium, including the many so-called ‘puzzles’ in the foreign exchange market (view post here).
Macro information inefficiency is consistent with the evidence of numerous behavioral biases of both retail and professional investors.
Trading towards information efficiency produces social and business value:
Investment managers can contribute to and benefit from information efficiency. A simple and practical approach is [i] to create indicators with meaningful macroeconomic and market information and [ii] to condense them into meaningful conceptual quantamental indicators and related trading factors that can guide investment strategies.
A quantamental indicator is a time series that represents the state of an investment-relevant fundamental feature in real time. The term “fundamental” here means that data inform directly on economic activity. This separates them from market data, which dominate conventional algorithmic trading, but provide such information only indirectly.
Fundamental features can be from the macroeconomic, social (macro behavioural), corporate and environmental space. Real-time dating means that indicator values correspond to the state of public information at the associated date. Values change in accordance with new data releases or re-estimations of relevant models. The impact of new data releases should be calculated based on data vintages, i.e. the state of time series at a specific release date. Re-estimation can be simulated through statistical learning.
The usage of quantamental indicators and factors has great benefits, particularly in the macro space:
For practical purposes and in order to avoid double-counting, misinterpreting and forgetting information it is helpful to structure quantamental factors into three groups.
Importantly, these three types of indicators are complementary, not competing. Indeed, powerful trading factors can be built on combinations of the above principal indicators. Thus, a price-value gap often arises as consequence of implicit subsidies, meaning that the subsidized asset becomes overpriced for a reason. Also, typically setback risks arise alongside subsidies due to positioning, causing sudden large losses to subsidy receivers.
Macro-quantamental indicators and trading signals are transformative technologies for asset management. That...
Jupyter Notebook Macro information state changes are point-in-time updates of recorded economic...
Jupyter Notebook Rising inflation is a natural headwind for equity markets in...
Jupyter Notebook of factor calculation Jupyter Notebook of statistical learning There is...
Jupyter Notebook Developing macro strategies for cross-country equity futures trading is challenging...
Jupyter Notebook Macro-quantamental scorecards are condensed visualizations of point-in-time economic information for...
Macrosynergy is a London based macroeconomic research and technology company whose founders have developed and employed macro quantamental investment strategies in liquid, tradable asset classes, across many markets and for a variety of different factors to generate competitive, uncorrelated investment returns for institutional investors for over eighteen years. Our quantitative-fundamental (quantamental) computing system tracks a broad range of real-time macroeconomic trends in developed and emerging countries, transforming them into macro systematic quantamental investment strategies. In June 2020 Macrosynergy and J.P. Morgan started a collaboration to scale the quantamental system and to popularize tradable economics across financial markets.